This paper presents an analytical approach of a socio-economic process occurring in smallholder farming systems in the south-west of the Brazilian Savannah and proposes agroforestry as an alternative strategy to increase farmers’ livelihood in a sustainable manner. The theoretical framework of this approach is based on the assessment of linkages between ecosystem attributes and resource management strategies at the farm-household level.
The
results
suggest that intensification and extensification are
no longer suitable for the system under the current technological and resource
conditions. Agroforestry might be an appropriate
alternative strategy for improving economic parameters while regenerating
resource deterioration.
Increasing demand for livestock foods offers countless opportunities for improving resource-poor farmers. Rapid urbanization, high income and population growth in developing countries are driving forces explaining this expansion (Delgado et al 1999). However, an increase of this demand is being supplied by large-scale industrialized and intensive farms. Resource-poor farmers are not able to meet properly this livestock market expansion unless sustainable-oriented technologies and policies are addressed.
In the Brazilian savannah,
resource-poor farmers based on live stock face serious difficulties to sustain
their family livelihoods. Significant poverty levels, emigration and resource
degradation are critical (Cunha et al 1994). The most
serious environmental constraint is pastureland degradation, which is
calculated covers about 10.3 millions hectares, nearly 50 percent of total
savannah pastures (Carvahlo 1998). There is strong
evidence that agroforestry can be an alternative
strategy to recover fundamental components and attributes of ecosystems while
reducing poverty and food insecurity for thousands of smallholders in
developing countries (
This paper attempts to provide a
sound understanding of the socio-economic process occurring in livestock-based
smallholder systems in the south-west Brazilian savannah in order to identify
opportunities for proper technological and policy interventions. Firstly,
aspects of sustainability of the system are analysed
via assessing linkages between farmer’s management decisions and attributes of
ecosystems. Secondly, agroforestry models are
simulated to assess impacts on the family income level and farm resources
allocation.
The study area is located in the south-west Brazilian savannah whose dualistic development pattern is typical in the whole region: mixed intensive mechanized agriculture for export-oriented commodities and traditional low-input agriculture practised by resource-poor farmers.
The study is mainly based on
farm-household data obtained from a survey in 1997. The random sample includes
all resource-poor family farmers in a micro-watershed (n=35). Statistical,
geographical and historical information complements the socio-economic data. A micro-economic
approach is used to estimate interrelations between selected ecosystems
attributes and resource management strategies. Multiple regression models and
Pearson’s correlation are the tools used to assess the nature of these
relationships. Comparative-static linear programming models are developed for assessing
impact. A basic model describing the current situation is compared with
possible future scenarios resulting from the adoption of agroforestry.
Stability, efficiency and
productivity are key properties for sustainable agro-ecosystems (Conway and Barbier 1990).
Stability is an attribute of ecosystems defined as the capacity of an ecosystem
to renew itself and to regenerate in front of disturbances in its natural
evolution (Redclift and Sage 1994). In productive
terms it refers, thus, to the ability of an ecosystem to maintain productivity
through time in face of long-term ecological constraints and social pressures (Altieri 1995). Normally, these constraints are relatively
continuous and expected and therefore farmers can face them by introducing
measures to counter their effects [A broad discussion regarding the properties of ecological systems
stability and resilience can be found in Holling
(1973). While resilience determines the
persistence of relationships within a system to absorb changes of state,
stability refers to the ability of a system to return to an equilibrium state
after a temporary disturbance]. The capability response of eco-systems will
depend on their intrinsic characteristics as well as on the nature of the
stress and shocks.
It is believed that, particularly
in the developing word, the disappointing adoption of management technologies
has been the major obstacle for achieving stable development (Laming and Ashby
1992). Especially in areas with low resource endowment, better management of
farm production systems enable farmers to minimize risks and withstand stress
and shocks (Altieri 1995). In this paper it is
assumed that farm management decisions have been strongly influenced by
prevalence of instability. The system stability could be measured indirectly
through instability sources-management decision relationships. Pearson’s
correlation is used to assess the nature of these associations.
Another ecosystem property explored here is resources productivity. A profitable agro-ecosystem is indispensable to increases physical and social well-being of the farmers (Barbier 1987). This indicator is assumed as the relationship of total revenues minus variable costs per unit of resources use. Influences of resources management decisions on resources productivity are tested by using econometric models.
Farm-family decisions expressed
as management strategies are taken in response to particular cultural,
socio-economic and physical factors. In this system, pastures account for
approximately 80 percent of land used (65ha) indicating the livestock
specialization. Improved pastures take into account the area in introduced
pastures and occupy less than a third of the total grassland. Cropping
intensity is quite low and takes into account the total cultivated crops on the
total cultivated area in the given year. The crops cultivated are maize, rice
and cassava and occupy nearly 8 percent of the farmland. Mechanisation,
defined as ploughing practices on small plots using
heavy rented tractors, is practiced by most of the farmers. Feeding livestock
area includes harvested grass and sugarcane production. This practice although
practiced by most of the farmers occupies very little of the farmland. Native
and forest vegetation remains only as some patch of gallery forest around the
streams. Only a third of the farmers maintain some land as fallow. Manure is
used to fertilise coffee or fruit trees on backyards
(see table 1).
Table 1: Resources management strategies |
||
Management strategies and land-use |
Coverage |
%
of farmers |
Mechanisation (ha) Improved
pastures (ha) Cropping
intensity (index) Feeding
livestock area (ha) Food
self-sufficiency (index) Native
pasture (ha) Forest (ha) Fallow (years) Manure (ha) |
2.98 16.0 0.13 3.12 0.59 36.8 6.20 4 -5 0.34 |
82 35 85 77 97 62 57 35 29 |
Table 2: Sources of instability grouped by
importance and scale levels |
|
Regional and sub-regional
level |
Climatic fluctuations |
|
Inefficient marketing |
|
High production costs |
Farm-household level |
Land scarcity-Capital scarcity |
Crops activities level |
Low soil fertility |
Livestock activities level |
Pastures degradation-Livestock under-nutrition |
Elements in
“bold” are highly important; others are of moderate importance |
The positive
relationship of food self-sufficiency and land scarcity contrasts with
processes happening in other savannah regions, where farming intensification is
reducing food production for self-consumption (Dos Santos et al 1998; Muriel
and Sebastian 1998). Food self-sufficiency is also positively related to
low soil fertility, water scarcity and inefficient marketing. These
relationships could be interpreted as a farmer insurance perception against
expected food shortages.
Table 3: Relationships
between resources management strategies and sources of instability |
|||||||
|
Resources management
strategy |
||||||
Sources of instability ¯ |
Mechanisation |
Food self-sufficiency |
Cropping
intensity |
Feeding
area |
Manure |
|
%
Native pastures |
Land scarcity |
0.35 * |
0.33 * |
0.29 * |
0.40 * |
|
|
|
Inefficient
marketing |
|
0.29 * |
|
0.41 * |
|
0.50 * |
-0.25 ** |
Liquidity
scarcity |
|
|
0.44 * |
|
|
|
|
Debts |
|
|
0.50 * |
0.39 * |
0.40 ** |
|
|
Low soil
fertility |
|
|
|
|
0.43 * |
-0.27 ** |
-0.22 ** |
*, ** Significance levels at 1% and 5%, respectively |
Resource productivity and resources management strategies
Productivity is considered the working capital, whereas labour productivity involves family and hired labour. Resources productivity presents a high heterogeneity in the farmer sample, with the higher variation in labour use (table 4). Some explanations could be found in factors like education level, family size and composition and hired labour availability (Santacoloma 2000).
Table 4: Resources use productivity |
|
Productivity of resources |
Mean |
Capital
(Reais/capital use) |
0.627
(0.405) |
Labour (Reais/ME) |
38,801
(37,532) |
Land (Reais/ha) |
1153 (921) |
ME: man-equivalent |
Multiple regression models were used to explain how resource management strategies affect the systems performance (table 5). The stepwise method was applied to select the variables that fully establish conditions of significance. From the set of resource management strategies only a few can significantly explain the resource productivity. From the results, mechanisation, which is a strategy oriented to intensify resources use, has a negative impact on capital and land productivity. Otherwise, forestland use, which favours fallow use, and consequently land extensification, has also negative impact on labour and land resources productivity. This apparent contradiction might indicate that the system is unsustainable given the resources and technologies available.
Some possible explanations are affordable when details are examined. Firstly, mechanisation is relying on heavy rented machinery. Most probably this technology is not only unsuitable for the ecosystem conditions, but it is also an inappropriate choice in economic terms. It is also possible to argue that due to the small proportion of forest land (table 1) this no longer represents an alternative for soil regeneration with economic implications.
Table 5. Multiple regression models |
||||||
Performance |
Standardised |
Significance of “t” |
F value |
Sig. of F |
Adjusted |
|
Capital |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
-0.223 |
0.015 |
|
|
|
|
|
-0.298 |
0.04 |
3.63 |
0.024 |
36% |
|
|
0.464 |
0.015 |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
0.039 |
|
|
26 % |
|
|
|
0.099 |
||||
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
0.06 |
2.69 |
0.091 |
21% |
|
|
-0.271 |
0.07 |
Positive impacts of native
pastures on capital and labour productivity could be
associated with less land deterioration being evident in the economic
indicators. Improved pastures are normally adopted when native pastures become
degraded. So, native pastures represent a positive indicator of sustainability.
This indicator should be not only its proportion within the land used, but also
its species composition (Fujisaka 1997). Negative
impacts of food self-sufficiency on capital productivity suggest negative
trade-offs between social and economic goals in the system. From the results
the need is evident to promote measures in order to recover the resource
productivity and by doing so to increase farmers’ livelihood opportunities. One
such measure is agroforestry.
Several benefits of integrating
trees into agricultural systems have been identified. Growing trees on the
farm helps to maintain agricultural productivity, enhance the supply of market
products, and contributes to risk reduction and management (
The study uses a linear
programming model for static comparative analysis. A basic model describing the
current situation is set up and validated. The basic model seeks to reflect the
defined reality using average parameters of the relation between input-output,
the level of activities and restrictions in the farm-families sample (Hazell and Norton 1986). The objective function is to
maximize family income subject to a set of resources and activities. Once
validated, the model is compared with possible scenarios resulting from the
application of the agroforestry strategies. The
static linear programming model in this analysis can be mathematically
represented as follows:
Max. Z = åPiXi - CiXi
Subject to åXiaij =bj , all j= 1 to m
and Xi = 0
all i= 1
to n
Where:
Z = objective function; Xi = level of activities, household and external relations; Pi = price of the output or service activity; Ci= cost per unit of the i input; aij = represents the functional constraints and are called input-output coefficient; and bj = the amount of j resource available.
Scenario A1: Integrating
nitrogen-fixing species into the fodder crops sub-system. In order to simplify
the model, and considering agronomic properties, information related to Cratylia argentea is
used. The main assumptions are based on results of experiments in
§ The production of Cratylia argentea per shrub would be 430 g DM/ha/year (leaves and soft stems), equivalent to 2.58 ton DM/ha/year at a plant density of 6,000 trees/ha.
§ Replacements of concentrate as supplementary feeding for livestock by the leguminous fodder, which is rich in crude protein and is highly digestible (Argel and Lascano 1998).
§ Increase in productivity of sugar cane and cutter grass by 15 percent due to improvements in the chemical traits of the soil (Isichei and Moughalu 1992 cited by Carvahlo 1998).
§ Partial replacement of maize as a rich-energy source of fodder for livestock, 40 percent by sugar cane and cutter grass.
§ Increase in milk production by 10 percent. It is a very conservative assumption considering that increases of more than 50 percent have been reported (Argel and Lascano 1998).
§ Cost of sowing and maintenance of the Cratylia argentea in the first year: 120 Reais/ha.
§ Increase of labour use is 35 person/days. This includes labour for sowing and cutting activities.
Scenario A2: Besides the assumptions for Scenario A1, a
mixture of nitrogen-fixing trees within the pastures in one hectare is added.
The specific assumptions are:
§ Increase of grass productivity of 20 percent due to impact of trees on soil features.
§ Increase in milk production of 20 percent in relation to the basic model due to synergetic effects of rich energy and rich protein sources of fodder.
§ Decrease in the use of maize for fodder up to 80 percent regarding the basic model and replacement with alternative sources of energy.
§ Additional costs of establishment of the pasture and sowing of trees.
Both the scenarios of agroforestry and silvo-pastoralism have significant positive impacts on the family income level. The introduction of agroforestry, Scenario A1 alone, would increase the family income by 4 percent. If, in addition, silvo-pastoralism is implemented, the increase in family income would be 11 percent (Figure 1). The impact on the cash balance would be positive and stronger than on the family income: the increase of cash availability is 28.2 percent for Scenario A1 and 98.9 percent for Scenario A2. Increases in cash availability would result from increases in cash inflows derived by higher sales of milk and maize, as well as by the decrease in feeding costs due to the elimination of concentrates.
Figure 1: Impact of agroforestry strategies into the Smallholder System
The levels achieved are very significant, although they hardly overcome the negative cash balance in the system. That is to say, in an optimal allocation of resources, the system would have positive economic results with strategies that are also environmentally friendly. However, additional incentives would be required to support this technological change during the transition phase. Both the knowledge regarding the better management of own resources and the financial resources for investments in capital naturally involve costs and risks. Institutional support to cover learning costs and investment costs are needed to encourage farmers to adopt this technology, which favours their short, medium and long term interests.
The most important impact on
resource use for the crop sub-system is the increase in maize production. It
might be that liberating a part of the production of maize for fodder could
stimulate its production for sales. This increase would be significantly higher
in Scenario A1 than in Scenario A2 (Table 6). Decreases in the live stock herd
(-10%) and cassava production (-23%) might be interpreted as a result of
competition for labour resources among crop, feeding
and live stock sub-systems. However, the no-feasible solution for the use of
permanent labour, due to its low coefficient values
in the model, does not allow us to give a clearer picture about this
conclusion. More significant result on the farm labour
force is the increase of demand for seasonal labour,
slightly higher in Scenario A1 than in Scenario A2. Apparently the integration
of agroforestry would not have any significant impact
in the allocation of labour force for off-farm
activities. Another significant and positive impact is on rented land with
increases to the upper limit in both tested scenarios.
In a general sense, the stronger impact of the tested
strategy on the resource allocation would be in Scenario A1, although better
economic profit would be obtained with Scenario A2.
Table
6: Impacts of
integrating agroforestry into the system on the use of resources
|
|||
Basic model |
Scenario A1 |
Scenario A2 |
|
Cash crops, ha |
|||
Maize |
1.16 |
1.85 |
|
Cassava |
0.33 |
0.25 |
|
Feed crops, ha |
|||
Sugar cane |
1.08 |
1.08 |
1.08 |
Cuttergrass |
0.82 |
0.82 |
0.82 |
Forage trees |
0 |
0 |
1 |
Live stock, units |
20 |
18 |
18 |
Rented land, ha |
3.06 |
5.0 |
5.0 |
Labour, units |
|||
Permanent |
0.52 |
nf |
nf |
Seasonal |
18.8 |
25.1 |
23.5 |
Off-farm |
124 |
124 |
124 |
nf: no feasible
solution |
The systems practiced by resource-poor farmers in the
south-west Brazilian savannah are no longer sustainable under the current
technological and resource conditions. Alternative strategies need to be
addressed. In scenarios of optimal allocation of resources, the integration of agroforestry into these systems would deliver positive
socio-economic impact. Its implementation would require additional
financial and labour investments from the farmers.
Specific training, extension and research on this subject, as well as financial
support, are complementary measures needed to successfully implement this
strategy.
Comments from John Dixon (FAO-AGSP) to a previous draft are very much appreciated.
Altieri M 1995 Agroecology. The science of sustainable
agriculture.
2nd edition. Westview Press
Argel P and Lascano C E 1998 Cratylia argentea: una nueva leguminosa arbustiva para suelos ácidos
en zones subhúmedas
tropicales. In: Tercera Conferencia
Electrónica de la FAO sobre Agroforestería para la
producción animal en Latinoamerica
Arnold J E M 1999 Economic factors in farmers adoption of forest product activities. http://www.fao.org/docrep/w3735e/w3735e19.htm
Barbier E 1987 The
concept of sustainable economic development. In.: Environmental Conservation.
Vol. 14
No 2. Pp 101-110
Botero R and Russo R 1998 Utilización de arboles y arbustos fijadores de nitrógeno in sistemas
sostenibles de producción animal en suelos ácidos tropicales. In:Tercera Conferencia Electrónica
de la FAO sobre Agroforestería para la producción
animal en Latinoamérica
Carvahlo M M
1998
Recuperação de pastagens degradadas em areas de relevo acidentado. In:
Recuperação de areas degradadas. Sociedade Brasileira de Recuperação de areas
degradadas. Pp 149-161
Carvahlo M M, Freitas V and Xavier D 1999 Comportamento de cinco leguminosas arbóreas exóticas em pastagem formada em solo de baixa fertilidade. In: Revista Arvore Vol 23 No 2 Pp 187-192
Cunha A, Mueller C, de Andrade E and da Silva J E 1994 Uma avaliação da sustentabilidade da agricultura nos Cerrados. In: Relatórios de Pesquisas. IPEA- Instituto de Pesquisa Económica Aplicada. Projeto PNUD/BRA/91/1014
Delgado C, Rosegrant M, Steinfeld H, Ehni S and Courbois C 1999 Livestock 2020: the next food revolution. 20020 Brief 61. http://www.ifpri.org/2020/briefs/number21.htm
Dos
Santos
N A, Lothoré A and Ayres M 1998
Renda na agricultura familiar. Um estudo de caso
no municipio de Silv(nia-Go. (Manuscript)
Projecto de P&D Embrapa Cerrados
Fujisaja S
1997 Personal communication, CIAT, Cali,
Colombia
Hazell
Peter B R and Norton Roger D 1986
Mathematical programming for economic analysis in agriculture.
Holling C S 1973 Resilience and stability of ecological systems. Annual Review of Ecology and Systematics. Vol 4 pp 1-23
Laming D L and Ashby J A 1992 Adoption of natural resource management practices by resource-poor farmers, in Zobish, Acceptance of soil and water conservation strategies and technologies. Witzenhausen, DITSL.
Muriel A-F and Sébastien B 1998 A intensificaçon leiteira no municipio de Silvânia-GO: as implicaçoes en termos de sistemas forrageiros e sistemas de produço. (Manuscript) CIRAD.EMBRAPA CPAC
Redclift M and Sage C 1994 Strategies for sustainable development. Local agendas for the southern hemisphere. John Wiley &
Sons,
Sanchez P, Izac A-M and Scott B 1999 Delivering on the promise of agroforestry. http://www.worldbank.org/cgiar/newsletter/sept99/agforest.htm
Santacoloma P 2000 An
Ecologically and Economically Balanced Development in the Brazilian Savannah : The Case of Irai de
Minas. Farming Systems and Resources Economics in the Tropics
No 36.
Solarte A 1997
Sustainable
Livestock Systems based on Local Resources: CIPAVs
Experiences. In: Second FAO Electronic Conference on Livestock Feed Resources
within Integrated Farming Systems. September 1996-February 1997
(the editors apologise for the delay in reviewing and editing this paper